Monday, May 29, 2023

Human adaptation to diverse biomes

 

From Science, May 12 2023, “Human adaptation to diverse biomes over the past 3 million years”

Our data-based diversity selection hypothesis may also add context to our more recent human history. According to our analysis, our genus Homo has adapted over the Pleistocene and migrated to areas with higher landscape diversity. Utilizing resources from various biomes provided a resilient and successful strategy over hundreds of millennia. However, during the Anthropocene, our species has caused a massive decline in global ecosystem diversity due to land use practices, gradually shifting away from integrated agricultural practices and toward monocultures. Modern humans have clearly taken an unprecedented path away from our ancestors’ resilience and diversity-based strategies.”

This paper offers a couple of tantalizing counters to the prevailing mythology of human evolutionary and migratory development.  It emphasizes the importance of adaptability, rather than the myth of our adaptation specifically to the African savannah, as a possible marker of human evolution: i.e., the history of early humans is one of becoming adapted to the planet as a whole rather than any particular biome, and when we examine the hundred thousand year old parts of ourselves, maybe that willingness to take part in the life of the planet is what we should be taking away as our story, rather than the conventional supports of patriarchy, male domination and violent survivalism.

A second counter is to the idea of diversity including moving the human species out into space via what is being called technological human adaptation, but may in fact be anything but.  Adaptation to diversity has to be measured in terms of what is available before and what after that adaptation: "adaptation" that moves a few billionaires and fools onto a planet inhospitable to advanced life, at the cost of further reducing diversity and the options available to the many on the home planet, cannot be categorized alongside the long history of humanity's adaptation to the biomes presented to it.

Saturday, October 3, 2020

What's a Battery? 2. Opportunity cost in the Two-Period Case: No Initial Storage

    A battery whose value is realized over two periods, starting from no initial storage (i.e., C0 = 0 or Cmin if the battery is represented as having a nonzero minimum energy state, but Cmin is not usable during period 0 or period 1) cannot discharge in period 0, assuming each period allows only one directional decision on energy usage.  If a single period can include both charge and discharge, then there may be multiple values associated with a single net charge or discharge, and the maximum net value may be taken as the value associated with an equivalent single decision to charge or discharge. 

    Period 0 requires a net charge greater than or equal to zero, and only the net energy resulting from the Period 0 charge is available at the beginning of Period 1.  The option value OValue(e1) is associated with the energy above Cmin available at the beginning of Period 1. 

    In the pure two-period model, energy remaining at the end of Period 1 has no value, so that the optionality value must exceed the energy value for the battery to be used for its optionality rather than its energy in Period 1; with no loss of generality, the option value may be taken to include energy value DValue(e1) if the energy value exceeds the option value.

    The battery in this case must receive, or expect to receive, revenues in Period 1 that exceed the costs of storing energy in Period 0.  If prices are known with certainty, the battery can be scheduled to charge enough to cover maximum discharge in Period 1 if the arbitrage is profitable.  In the case that prices are not known, a schedule may not yield profits with certainty, though it may in expectation.  Of course, I want to apply this model to the case of participation in an energy market, that is to say a case of repeated market runs, but I’ll note the model at this point isn’t quite ready to be used for that purpose: for one thing, when a battery charges because of expected revenues from discharge, but doesn’t discharge, that alters the next market run’s initial storage from the “no initial storage” case.

    The issue of end-of-horizon storage can be assumed away by requiring the battery be returned to its “no initial storage” state at the end of Period 1.  We can imagine real world cases that approximate such a constraint, such as batteries with operational constraints that require zero storage at the end of the scheduling horizon (perhaps because the use for charging in each repeated market’s “Period 0” is contractually required, as it is for solar+storage hybrid resources), or system conditions that very reliably make use of a battery’s entire storage capacity by the end of the scheduling horizon.  In such cases, every day is a new day unless the battery operator is employing game-theoretic strategies that yield differential outcomes against other strategic players (i.e., partial or no combined charge-discharge schedules on some days in exchange for other more lucrative days).

    Aside from making a self-scheduling discharge to charge and then discharge based on forecast values (more typically, electricity prices), another application of the “no initial storage” case that doesn’t require modeling of repeated market runs is to use the concept of a contingent two-part bid, often referred to as an “arbitrage bid” by those who would like to see something like it implemented in wholesale markets.  The contingent two-part bid consists of a paired charge bid and discharge bid, such as that one of the two bids is accepted only if the other is also accepted.  The beauty of reducing the battery model to two periods with no initial storage is that it reveals the difficulties, not to say impracticality, of accepting contingent two-part bids from more than one battery: although the difference between “discharge price” and “charge price,” also known as the arbitrage, can be nicely ordered among batteries, there is not necessarily a monotonic ordering of the bid pairs behind these arbitrages based on the market objective function (usually the minimization of total electricity costs required to match total supply and total demand).  In fact, contingent bids for multiple two-period batteries would require a mixed integer linear program formulation which by itself could be an arbitrarily hard combinatoric problem: potentially harder, in other words, than the traditional electric system unit commitment problem that serves as the backbone of all modern electricity markets.

    This very simple model allows consideration of a contentious point in the calculation of “default energy bids” that may in principle be imposed on batteries as a version of cost-based bidding by system operators or regulators, in cases where market power is or might be exercised to the disadvantage of the market as a whole.  The California ISO, in its ESDER 4 market enhancements initiative, proposed a default energy bid calculation as

    DEB = max( charging cost/efficiency + a variable cost term, opportunity cost of discharge)

    In the two period case, it’s clear that the variable cost term can be adjusted for any single market run to equal (opportunity cost of discharge – charging cost/efficiency), so that the first term in the maximum equals the second.  Discussion of the DEB calculation has focused on the question of whether the opportunity cost term is needed or legitimate in the day ahead market, when the CAISO as system operator can at least in theory determine the optimal combination of charging and discharge that maximizes the value of the battery. 

    A proposal not to include opportunity cost in the DEB calculation must be based on an assumption that a variable cost component, which as a “master file” parameter does not vary from one day to the next, is equivalent to an opportunity cost component based on the anticipated benefit of using the battery in the current market versus reserving it for future use.  But the terms are clearly not equivalent under any price uncertainty: in particular, the combination of a charging cost term that varies daily (per the DEB proposal) with an invariant variable cost term will clearly not be equivalent to an opportunity cost term that varies daily.  

    It is clear that a battery operator’s objective (and it might be supposed, the CAISO’s long-term objective) should be to see the battery discharged in markets with the highest values over the lifetime of the battery, and that the variable cost term by itself would not lead to such highest value discharges; instead, it would lead to the battery being discharged in every market for which discharge was economic (i.e., had non-negative net revenue) until the battery’s degradation made such discharge impossible.   

Sunday, September 27, 2020

What’s a Battery? 1. Definition and Formulation (the Two Period Case)

               First principles: a battery is a machine with limited capacity to store energy, whose primary purpose is to store energy for later use.  This definition captures the need for a battery to be a machine (excluding living creatures whose metabolic functions might be described in this way); whose capacity is limited (i.e., the boundaries of the description of the machine must include its limits, in contrast to hypothetical machines with internal capabilities to increase their capacities, such as systems storing compressed gasses or liquids in underground caverns of unknown size); with a primary purpose of storing energy (as opposed to machines for which storage is an incidental function or part of a different productive process); and whose storage is for use later in time (i.e., it is unable to borrow energy from a later point in time for use now, although a current use could certainly be accompanied by a plan to add back to available energy at a later time).

From this definition a simple formal math representation may be derived.  A battery’s limited capacity may be represented by C.  At least two time periods should be designated, a period in which energy is stored and a later period in which energy is used.  If the entire capacity of a battery is considered usable, then efficiency losses during use (sometimes called “discharge”) are internalized in the representation of available energy e; that is, energy up to the amount e is considered usable, although in fact the energy required to create e “units of usable energy,” whatever that means, might be larger than e.  If the process (sometimes called “charging”) of storing e units of usable energy required e units of energy, that process would be perfectly efficient with respect to this representation.  In general, ec units of energy are required to store e units of energy, where ec > e.  If e/ec does not vary depending on current storage or the amount stored in a given period, e/ec may be considered a constant efficiency factor denoted eff.  The amount of energy required to charge the battery fully may be represented by EC, where EC > C, and EC*eff=C for constant eff.

The implications of this simplest battery model for representing decisions about whether to charge or discharge are:

1.      A battery may begin the current period in a state of energy storage C0 between 0 and C.

2.      The battery may charge up to (C – C0) units of energy in the current period.  Charging will require an amount of energy greater than (C – C0) and less than EC.

3.      The battery may discharge up to C0 units of energy in the current period.

4.      The battery operator may decide to retain or increase energy stored until the end of the current period in order to have the option of using it in a future period.

5.      The optionality of future use does not equate to future use.

The economic value of this simple battery is maximized when the charge/discharge decisions made in the current period 0 and the later period 1 are such that they maximize the objective function “Maximize (Value of discharge in period 0 – Cost of charge in period 0) + (Value of optionality of discharge in period 1)”, which may be written

     Max DValue(d0) – Cost(ec0) + OValue(e1)

    where 1. d0 <= C0

               2. ec0 * eff = c0 < (C – C0)

               3. e1 = C0 + ec0 * eff – d0

               3. OValue(e1) >= DValue(e1)

Constraint 3 is a statement that the value of either optionality or energy beyond period 1 is zero, so that if the battery is used not for energy but some other purpose covered by “optionality,” that optionality must have a value higher than the value of discharged energy in that period.  The optionality value may be considered to include the value of energy beyond the horizon of the problem to be solved: i.e., it includes a liquidation value.

Tuesday, June 2, 2020

Last Whole Earth Wayback Machine

Periodically I pull out my big fat copy of The Last Whole Earth Catalog and peer back into my youthful history, into what on this day I must call the history of my white privilege.  The particular privilege I enjoyed in my youth was certainly never available to people of color in the day, and today it isn't even available to most white kids: it was the privilege of economic security so assured that I could choose not to work, not to aspire, to waste my time and not worry about the effect of that malingering on my future. 

Last Whole Earth youth culture was a mix of love-ins, hippie-by-mail culture, and ultimately going to an experimental college where almost everyone's aspirations were pretty similar to my own.  But the catalog allowed all sorts of other weird stuff to enter the mix. 

When I perused the volume a couple of days ago, the first item my eyes alit upon was an entry for a Craftsman half-inch heavy duty drill costing under $50, which led me to look immediately for its equivalent on Amazon today: looks like the comparable item costs about $250, which doesn't seem a bad scaling for fifty years.  I was struck by its having been Sears house brand at the time, more or less the equivalent of Amazon's house brand products (though the latter have all been shoddily made in my experience), with the Last Whole Earth Catalog itself acting as the mystical soul-transmigrator which transmits essence of Sears to essence of Amazon. 

In fact, a lot of my high school infatuation with the Catalog probably sprang from a similar obsessive infatuation with the fat Sears catalogs that came to our house before Christmas (I was mesmerized by the toy section, of course, but also by the pages of fishing equipment that I never had the least use for); and the Amazon algorithms strive for the same serendipitous associations the Catalog achieved by means of its amateurish yet sublime editors and reviewers.

My second draw at the well brought something more sinister to light, the draw that libertarianism had for scruffy as well as fascistic baby boomers.  Ayn Rand and Milton Friedman are cited with approval by the reviewers (and by Stewart Brand, the presiding host of the book) as saying true things about power and the economy. 

In retrospect, that bias might help to explain both the half century of growth in the tech sector, and the kind of libertarianism now practiced by Trumpist baby boomers who probably have some nostalgia for their excesses of the 1970's when they're not attending evangelical services or target practice.  The judgments of that era, like those of today's know-nothings, were from the gut and very prone to flush the good (such as civil rights and poverty reductions achieved) out with the visibly bad  (Vietnam as seen by both hippies and fascists).  We really must be more thoughtful than that now.


Sunday, May 31, 2020

Network Effect

I finished reading Martha Wells' new Murderbot novel Network Effect this morning.  The previous books in the series, the Murderbot Diaries, are four... novellas is what they were called when as a voracious reader of science-fiction I made my way through all the early Nebula award winners.  And in terms of the criteria for awards in science-fiction, that is what they are, all under 40,000 words.  The earlier Murderbot stories were however all published as individual books, so it might be more accurate to refer to them as short novels, without any of the embellishments that once implied not only a shorter word count, but also a particular kind of dramatic form peculiarly its own.

The Nebula awards, and the Hugo awards as well, set out a continuum of short story, then novelette, then novella, then novel.  Novellas were defined as being between 15,000 and 40,000 words, not enough to amount to a novel as defined by science-fiction publishers, but far in excess of the tautness of the short story format.  In mathematical terms, a novella occupies a finite interval of possible narrative length whereas the novel can be infinitely long; hence a novella must partake of the finitude of the short story even as it stretches.  Commonly, a novella used to serve as a kind of trial run for a full-length novel (and the novelette, when not just a long short story, could similarly serve as a kind of outline).  In the case of the Murderbot Diaries, however, the stories are each fully realized and contribute to the development of the protagonist, which culminates in Network Effect.

Thus another way to approach the Murderbot books is as a single serial work, and for those interested in reading them, it's pretty important to do so in their intended order.  Martha Wells is a marvelous author of serial works -- I can make that assertion based on the complete arc to date of the Murderbot books, as well as based on another book of hers I've read, The Wizard Hunters, first in her series "The Fall of Ile-Rien."  Wells takes full advantage of the ability to refer to events offstage, which have a resonance whether one has read the original source or not, in adding dimension to events and characters who would otherwise require too much space or not move the story along at just the right pace.  In the Murderbot stories the pace is almost always hell-bent, but the Ile-Rien book used the same devices in a much more leisurely and intricate way.

But the greatest strength and pleasure of the Murderbot stories is, as I suggested, the realization of the central character, both human and not, one of the best usages of the artificially intelligent superhero trope you'll ever encounter.  Depending on your tolerance or need for science-fictional escapism, you should definitely put them on your list.

Saturday, May 30, 2020

The Lady from Shanghai

Friday being "family movie night" here, we watched Orson Welles' The Lady from Shanghai this week, it being the May entry in Charla's 2020 film noir calendar.  I have to place it among the strangest movies I've seen, up there with the entire ouevres of David Lynch or Luis Bunuel or Maya Deren.  I received it as a complete surprise, never having been warned of its strangeness.

Thinking about movies like The Lady from Shanghai made in the period right after the end of World War II, I hypothesize that creative ferment had multiple sources and could yield messy results.  I wanted to be smart here and refer to the specific technological advances that must have happened in movies over the course of the war years, but my googlesearch didn't yield anything specific. 

It seems clear from the variety of locations used over the movie's journey from New York to San Francisco that the freedom to travel (after the restrictions imposed by the war) was liberating for Orson Welles' creative juice-flowings.  The movie includes a whole anthology of mini-movies enclosed in the overarching structure of the story.  The Caribbean picnic, the Acapulco layover, the Chinese theater... each of these sequences is etched in my memory album already.  These sequences and others are masterpieces of cinematography, really, attested to by the fact that the best article I've found on the web about the movie so far focuses on the cinematographer rather than Welles.

What is puzzling about The Lady from Shanghai is that the acting is stylized to the point of being inhuman, the writing laugh-out-loud pretentious, and the story a gobbledygook mishmash of fantasy and plot points that makes no sense except in an assumed dream world within the cranium of Orson Welles.  Puzzling because Columbia must have known they were taking a flyer on a story both unsympathetic and confusing, with only the face and body of Rita Hayworth to pull in the masses.

Hypothesis one: The Lady from Shanghai takes its liberties from the world of "theater" (pronounced in as high-falutin a manner as possible) in which primadonna actors pronounce and enunciate and preen and strut rather than interact or attempt to convince the audience that what they are doing is natural.  This fits an image I still have of the decade prior to my birth as a period, now identified as "middle-brow," in which the number of Americans who hungered for intellectual nourishment and high art was greater than ever before or since, and that ambition was fostered because it fit our Cold War need for exceptionalism so well.

Hypothesis two: Orson Welles made movies as a hybrid of radio and visual scene construction, and wasn't concerned about the seamless integration of the two.  If you were to listen to the dialogue of The Lady from Shanghai on the radio, the anti-naturalistic speaking of the actors would be exactly what was expected and needed for transmission over the era's highly unreliable networks; the lack of visual cues would probably sometimes, but not always, make the story more confusing and wild than it already is.

Hypothesis three: Welles' anti-naturalism is a deliberate attempt to bring the incredible into a contemporary environment, a form of mythologizing or mythic storytelling that can't be judged by any normal criteria of credibility.  The character played by Welles combines superhuman capabilities and charisma with seeming passivity in the face of others' manipulations: he's a mix of Odysseus, Orpheus and Hercules (at a minimum).  And Rita Hayworth plays multiple incarnations of the Goddess over the course of the film and up through its stupefying conclusion.

So good and so bad...  I'm not willing to recommend the movie, but I recommend that you watch it.

Thursday, May 28, 2020

Escape from Facebook?

On Facebook today I wrote my status as:

Trying to figure out how I can stay connected with my friends and not support the evil that is Mark Zuckerberg.

This in response to Zuckerberg's personal defence of Trump's lying advertisements on his platform versus the comments posted on Twitter indicating that the Donald's allegations of the fraudulent nature of mail-in voting are themselves false and harmful.

Beyond that, Zuckerberg has been raising funds for Trump, and taking personal meetings. That adds up to more than the expected trimming political behavior of corporate moguls (not to say that that might not be pretty evil in itself).

I got lots of helpful comments to my post on Facebook, as well as one old friend from many years back contacting me on LinkedIn to encourage my separation from FB. Among the comments was one from my sister:

Or how about an Alva mailing list or newsletter? Is that too old fashioned? I'd subscribe!!

Considering that comment, I realized that I can attempt to do just that with this blog, which has been moribund as you'll see for more than a year, but which was intended to serve just such a purpose, once upon a time.  So I'm starting up my blog journal once again.  Consider it an Alva mailing list or newsletter.  And I promise to try to keep it up if some of my friends subscribe; and I promise even harder to try to keep it up if some of my friends occasionally comment on my posts.  The equivalent of a "Like" or emoji would be perfectly fine...

And if you choose to do the same, I will subscribe to your blog too.

What do you say?

Thursday, January 24, 2019

Not all in yet


The presidential campaign of 2020 keeps to its early timetable as of Monday morning, as Kamala Harris announced her candidacy for President.  I haven’t previously resonated with her major policy platforms — Medicare for All as a solution to American healthcare, and a large wealth transfer tax to increase working people’s incomes — but I’ll look more seriously at them now that she’s a candidate and I’m not associating Medicare for All strictly with Bernie Sanders and the Democratic Socialists.  Her tax credit actually is very reminiscent of Sherrod Brown’s tax credit proposals, though it may differ in specifics.  And I admire her for taking the step to run explicitly for the office at this point, and to try her particular way of organizing the coalition she wants to elect her, which seems clearly not to be the same approach as that taken by the candidates appealing to Iowa or New Hampshire or people who voted for Obama but then Trump in the Midwest.  She’s starting her campaign on Sunday in Oakland, and I’ll be there to hear her, even if I don’t decide to support her to the exclusion of others.  

This “all in” terminology is not my generation, or at any rate it’s not me.  I’ll vote for anyone against Trump, and I want to see someone run who can defeat Trump, and beyond that I want to vote for someone I basically agree with — the combination of those three axioms leads to conclusions such as: 

(1) In California, I wouldn’t feel compelled to vote for someone I truly disagree with, like Bernie Sanders, even in the general election.  A three million or more vote cushion means I don’t ever have to take responsibility for a Democratic defeat based on how I vote in California. 

(2) Most other candidates I’ve heard about I’d give at least some money to during the general election campaign, to meet my responsibility of doing something positive to get a Democrat elected over Trump. 

(3) But in the next two years prior to the general election, I’m much more likely to give money to someone with an agenda I agree with, such as Warren or Brown or maybe Harris, than I am to somebody who just wants to be President.  I don’t know which of those categories Julian Castro or Kristin Gillibrand is in, yet, but I’ll try to find out.

Wednesday, January 23, 2019

The edge of chaos


A couple of walks on Sunday listening to “The Edge of Chaos,” by Dambisa Moyo — walking to Safeway to get cereal and milk earlier in the morning, and then around the lake in the afternoon.  I haven’t quite gotten to the gist of the book, the arguments for changes that go against the grain of the commonplace, yet, but Moyo summarizes the issues of the day in a way that at least requires me to think about them, and question their solubility within the limits of what’s currently available in the political process.  

That said, I do believe some candidates, especially Elizabeth Warren and Sherrod Brown right now, are putting forward substantial proposals for change and redress that could appeal to more than just the liberal-progressive axis of the Democratic Party — earned income and child tax credits should be winners for anyone in the majority of relatively low wage people in the country, unless they’re being completely bamboozled by their preachers.  And Warren’s proposals to put restraints on corporate and financial behavior are consistent at once with Bernie Sanders’ and Trump’s rhetorics and the thinking of moderate Democratic groups like Third Way.  

I can only hope that these ideas, combined with genuine empathy and outrage at the state of unbalanced advantage to the extremely wealthy and to corporations run by hedge funds (and hence indifferent to any standard of value other than short-term stock price), might make them as candidates more formidable than the less experienced candidates running on diversity issues and tacking the larger problems on only after attaching to their demographics.  

Jay Inslee’s interesting too, but is running entirely on the issue of climate change, which taken by itself is more likely to be taken as one more progressive left coast boutique issue by the heartland, or worse, combined with Green New Deal proposals that throw cost-benefit analysis out along with free market economics as having any role in addressing climate change.

Tuesday, January 22, 2019

Old folks and youngsters


Walking along the Embarcadero to the ballpark at lunch last Friday, past Red’s Java House and the pier warehouses, was a palimpsest on all the walks I’ve done like that over the years, since I was introduced to Red’s by William Talcott.  The sweep of the promenade is the same, though it seemed wider today for some reason — it does that when there are high clouds covering the sky and the Bay Bridge is captured within that dome, but clearly.  At the ballpark rather than turning back I took Second Street, again the palimpsest but this time a palimpsest of modifications within the basic theme, the street a kind of fugue on commerce and where people go for lunch.  Nothing lasts but everything’s the same.  Everyone seemed to be “a kid,” meaning a post-millennial, kids in their twenties, which had me counting the years to figure out whether they could be my grandkids or great-grandkids.  Fixing on an age of parenting at 23, as was the case with Mom and Dad when I was born in 1957, had I followed their example I’d now have sixteen year old grandchildren, so no great-grandkids yet, and certainly none in their twenties, but the distance was great, not so much in terms of what they know or how they think, which is pretty uniform in San Francisco, I’m not much different from them in that way, but in the mere duration and enduring of events, whether measured by the narrative of mediated news or in the character of the city and the Bay Area itself, invisible changes that become visible, changes that aren’t changes, and changes that finally are changes.  How are they to trust that what I point to as experience is that and not a fabrication meant to divert from the main event or the thrust of what’s being done to them by forces beyond their control.  When I was in my twenties I certainly didn’t hold my world in common with people in their sixties: one the one hand their lives had a different weight, the result of great wars and technological change I suppose; and on the other hand I supposed their experience to be merely residual to my own.

Monday, January 21, 2019

"The Meaning of Belief," by Tim Crane

I found Tim Crane's approach to relations between atheists ("we atheists," I should state clearly) and the religious far more satisfactory than the New Atheism's dogmatics as I understand them.  On the other hand, I'm not sure that the New Atheism's dogmatics really exist except as essayists' proposals -- they don't represent anything that's been agreed on, a consensus that is to say, or anything that has been tested for effectiveness.  Crane's approach isn't really satisfactory either, but that's on the premise held by so many British philosophers that nothing is ever really satisfactory, and that such limitations should be accepted and even made the foundation of a way of moving forward.  I spent twenty plus years as a practicing Catholic who didn't really believe in any of the dogma of the faith, so I can testify to the accuracy of Crane's emphasis on identity and a sense of a need for greater meaning, as opposed to any pseudo-scientific mythology, as the base of religious practice for many.  The only area in which I think Crane really falls short is in his willingness to place very little blame for violence on religious affiliation; this doesn't invalidate his argument, but it causes me to wonder why he felt it so important to attribute similar levels of violence to non-religious groups throughout the twentieth century.  Christians were deeply complicit in the Holocaust, on the one hand; and the violence that led to mass deaths via imprisonment and famine in the Soviet Union and China were not the result of non-religious group practice equivalent to that of ISIS, say, but rather the practices of totalitarian governments.  Such distinctions are meaningful to me, but seemingly not to Crane.

Mo' more nukes


The main speakers at the Commonwealth Club’s “Climate One” last Thursday were advocating for either a little or a lot of nuclear to be built on an emergency basis to address climate change, depending on the stage of their argument.  Their foil was a California renewable energy consultant advocating for the standard “solar + storage” model of how we’ll get through the perils of a system mostly made up of intermittent resources.  The main speakers advocated for not closing Diablo as if this were a relatively costless decision, rather than a political process almost certainly doomed, which is I think how PG&E saw it when they announced the plant’s scheduled closing.  They conveniently disregarded the closure under duress of San Onofre a couple of years earlier due to manifest failures in maintenance and materials.  On the other hand, their argument that solar and wind, even augmented by a reasonable amount of battery resource, cannot possibly lead to a fossil-free power system is I think correct.  If the solution to baseload needs, dispatchability during prolonged periods of low intermittent resource generation, and seasonal fluctuations is not nuclear plants, what is it?  There are at least a couple of existing technologies that could meet the need: long=term gravity-based storage, and hydrogen production and later re-use for generation or transportation.  But neither of these technologies is in fact either economic or easily put in place at scale (even if not economic) at this juncture.  Still, building nuclear plants in large numbers is a plan that would take at least a decade to come to fruition even if the right people were somehow placed in power; and the storage and hydrogen technologies are equally likely to come to maturity in that time frame, if fully supported by some government somewhere.

Sunday, January 20, 2019

Of bankruptcies and Brexits


It was odd that though I spent most of my time for days thinking through the implications of my employer’s failure (and by association my own), I felt more in command of my fate last Wednesday than I did earlier in the week, when I deliberately clouded my mind and determined to accept the comforting nostrums given to us in Monday’s series of town halls and meetings.  I may in fact be wrong in my assessments, but the sheer act of working through the appearance of a logical sequence of events provided me with more of a sense that I was an active participant in the process, rather than a passive spectator or victim being asked to keep to a holding pattern until further notice.  Overlaid on my “thinking through,” and the conversations I had in which I tried to do that thinking aloud and see if it still held together, was a half hour of listening to the British parliament debate and then vote on a vote of no confidence, which somehow reinforced my conviction that I was approaching events in the right way: the British debate, unlike a comparable American political debate, seemed forthright, clear, intelligible and yet more intelligent than I could possibly have managed to be in such a setting, one in which every statement was subject to uproarious contention but at the same time equally uproarious support, and in which the quality of speaking was itself a subject of debate and almost of critique in the course of coming to a very serious conclusion.

Wednesday, November 1, 2017

Ghosts of the California Genocide, Part 3

The third painting I intended to look at on my unpresented tour was by Albert Bierstadt, well-known for his majestic pictures of Yosemite (often with Indian villages or groups of Indians situated on the valley floor framed by the enormous granite cliffs on all sides) and for the finished painting "Last of the Buffalo," for which the De Young has a study:


"Last of the Buffalo" captures a moment as if it were a continuing and essential part of the life of the Plains, even as it states by its title that its evocation is, rather, of the notion that the Indians are passing away, like the buffalo, into a gone world.  Benjamin Madley in An American Genocide describes how the myth of the inevitable passing of the Indians was used as a way of justifying, sanitizing, and finally forgetting the acts of destruction by invaders that caused that "passing."

The painting I had wanted to look at, "California Spring," has been one of my favorites in the "Hudson River" landscape gallery of the De Young for many years, and I've frequently looked at it on other docent tours for its pastoral peacefulness, its situation in a part of the Sacramento Delta that can be visited less than an hour away from San Francisco, its tiny thumbnail of the state capitol building on the horizon, and the magnificent weather effects of the storm in the middle distance, backlit by the emerging sun.


But now there's another resonance in the painting for me: the realization that this European-style pastoral landscape can only exist because of the active destruction of the Indian-shaped landscape (and its sources of all that was needed to support the lives of the local Indians for thousands of years perhaps), first by the Spanish and Californio pastoralists who brought herds of cattle to the state, and then by the more systematic genocidal policies of the Californian and U.S. governments and their gold-hungry invading co-conspirators.



Monday, October 30, 2017

Ghosts of the California Genocide, Part 2

A few feet away from the baskets is the painting Sacramento Indian by Charles Christian Nahl (California's first significant artist, according to Wikipedia, and in the Madley book, the primary documenter of Indian life at the moment of its destruction), made for Milton Slocum Latham, a Southerner and Democratic politician who sat in the U.S. House of Representatives between 1850 and 1852 (when eighteen treaties with California Indian tribes that would have allocated land to the tribes were refused by the U.S. Senate under the pressure of white Californian politicians and newspapers).

The "Sacramento Indian" is portrayed as tamed, an essential distinction for the invaders who shaped the state of California and committed genocide in the first two decades of the state's history.  Wild Indians were categorized and treated as wild animals, with no more rights than other dangerous fauna (another painting at the De Young by Nahl depicts a hunter seated with a dead mountain lion lying before him, reminiscent of the Trump brothers on African safari, but also of the way in which animals and Indian are arranged deliberately in this painting).  The man's expression seems to capture something about both his own strength of character and the impossible danger of his position, even as he sits for the portrait with dignified stiffness.


Also in the museum is the wooden mantelpiece that must have dominated the interior of the Thurlow Mansion, taken over by Latham after Thurlow's bankruptcy, and evoking the brutal aristocratic life of an English hunting lord.


And another painting made not long after the portrait of the Sacramento Indian depicts the bustle of the Sacramento train station a couple of decades later, after the end of the period of systematic Indian genocide.  There are no Indians in this painting.




Sunday, October 29, 2017

Ghosts of the California Genocide, Part I


I had two tours at the De Young Museum today, neither of which had any takers.  I took for the subject matter of the second, which goes by "Three Masterpieces in Thirty Minutes" on the marquee, the spectral shadows in the museum of the genocide of California's Indians.  Not a happy subject; but appropriate perhaps for Halloween because these presences have been occupying my own mind like pipe-banging ghosts since I started reading Benjamin Madley's An American Genocide about this crucial chunk of California history, missing in my own picture of the narrative until now.

I began my hypothetical tour by looking at this large early 20th century Pomo burden basket.  Woven tightly enough to hold water or cooking coals, California Indian baskets have been seriously (passionately) collected since just after the period of the extermination of almost all the Indians themselves.  Madley dates the genocide from 1846 to 1873, and sees a reduction in population over the period of something like 80%, a reduction to invisibility as far as most of us who live in the state were and are concerned.  The large burden basket has a fantastic optical banding of overlapping and crossing spirals around a monumental form.


Another vitrine contains a series of baskets that diminish in size down to a truly miniaturist scale, barely larger than a nickel.  Like the large burden basket, all of them were made from materials available in the immediate environment of California, prepared to be suitable to their purpose.  The baskets thus speak to the primary rationale for the particular egregiousness of the California genocide, as compared to the many massacres carried out over the rest of the North American continent: the "wild" Indians, because their ways of living on the land were so seemingly unsophisticated and invisible, were regarded as animals.  The justification of murder and slavery followed accordingly and quite explicitly.  And the end result?  An invisibility, the baskets aside, that allows contemporary Californians to still doubt the claims made by the remaining descendents of survivors of the genocide.   


Tuesday, July 11, 2017

David Lynch, the man from another place

David Lynch: The Man from Another PlaceDavid Lynch: The Man from Another Place by Dennis Lim
My rating: 5 of 5 stars

I loved this book, which I listened to on Audible as an accompaniment to the new Twin Peaks shows. It's defiantly middle-brow, in love with popular culture but unafraid to refer to any aesthetic or philosophic movement that might be a good point of reference for a reader (or group of readers in discussion) mulling Lynch's work over, clearly written and with a personal point of view. It's a keystone for me in thinking about the structure of art between 1974, when my English teacher Mrs. Greening put me onto the Theater of the Absurd, and the present. The other thing I really like about Dennis Lim's writing on Lynch is that it doesn't devalue failures (of different magnitudes and for different real-world and interior reasons) in describing the career of an artist -- a worthy antidote to our equally success-corrupted and failure-corrupted art culture of 2017.


View all my reviews

Saturday, November 14, 2015

Billionaire

The bombings in Paris: political football of the lowest order, on the part of the Republican candidates for President of the U.S.A.; possible repercussions to the absorption of Syrian refugees by the E.U. (the U.S.A. has never been about to take any significant numbers, so nothing really changes even if Trump whines about not taking any -- too expensive to bring them here, on strictly utilitarian grounds, obviously); what might someday look like the beginning of ISIS's endgame.  Urban terrorism in the West has always been really terrifying but not in any way an existential threat to our existence as a mass of nearly a billion relatively rich people.  Urban terrorism triggers technological and legal responses that ultimately reduce its effects and get the killers, at some sacrifice of liberty and decency -- but did I mention those aren't the values I bring to my analysis of our national interests?

Anyway, in the meantime I'm playing with increasing obsessiveness this marvelous little mobile game called "Billionaire," which requires the player to trade off risk, labor, and time for return in fairly intricate ways that fairly in my mind mimic real economic decision-making.  Time enables one to generate income from a variety of investments, but there is little compounding effect from any one investment: upgrades yield only marginal improvements to return, pretty much like real investments in mature industries.  Risk is represented as legal risk: the more criminal an investment option in the game, the higher its risk.  A high risk profile pretty much ensures that one will spend most of one's time in prison, not able to do anything to generate additional income (though it appears one's investments continue to accumulate in the meantime); and there is an upper limit to the amount of risk one can take on, in absolute terms, so ultimately investments have to be allocated.  Risk can be mitigated by contributing to philanthropic "social" investments with negative risk profiles.  Labor allows one to accelerate, by repeated finger taps that would resonate with any animal psychologist, the building of either money-making or philanthropic investments in order to maximize the value of one's portfolio.  The velocities of the game are two: the accumulation of cash, always slow relative to one's total wealth or ability to invest in new things; and one's personal attention to the game, making sure that not too many investments "max out" and stop accumulating, and rebalancing based on the aforementioned considerations.  It's a lot like managing real money, although there's absolutely nothing to spend it on but more investments...

Friday, November 6, 2015

Feast of All Saints (Saint Paul)

My noon Highlights tour last Sunday (November 1) had "Saints" as its theme in honor of the feast day.  I didn't mention my own atheism to the marvelous group of people who did the tour with me, certainly not wanting to influence their response to the art or my thoughts with what might be reasonably interpreted as a twist of the knife.

We started the tour with the work above, Lorenzo di Niccolo's fourteenth century image of Saint Paul holding sword and book.  The web image does no justice at all to the luminosity of the red, orange and gold of the painting, which could have been painted yesterday rather than six hundred years ago (and I don't know the extent of recent restoration, so some of that luminosity might be a result of that rather than sheer survival).  Both the coloring and the intensity of Saint Paul's face and gaze call the viewer with a kind of personal reach quite different from neighboring paintings of the Madonna or Christ.  I asked a question of the group, something to the effect of "What does this painting convey about sainthood?"  The answer of a young man matched mine: the saint is looking at me, reaching out to me, attesting to his humanity.  The paintings of saints in the collection, even in this semi-medieval period, are all portraits of a sort, meant to imagine human beings with certain capabilities or meanings, but to really imagine them, to identify them as real individuals at the same time that they are categories or types or characters.

Saturday, February 21, 2015

Startups

The Wall Street Journal story on February 19 about startups valued at more than a billion was pretty fascinating (I thought).  There were a lot of stories I was already aware of -- in particular, I'd heard the founders of DocuSign, Eventbrite, and Taskrabbit (the first two in the billion dollar club) speak engagingly at a "Tech Founders Forum" event sponsored by Fortune magazine a few weeks back.  In the "fascinating" category was the claim that Jessica Alba's company Honest Co. was among those valued at more than a billion.  I had that info-bit in my mind when having a really enjoyable and inspiring conversation with the founder and owner of Magic Fairy Candles, flying from Colorado back to Oakland last Thursday, hearing her story about how her business had grown and her initial statement that she was far from that startup world, and then realizing that her business was in fact part of that "eco-system" because she's in fact part of the same world (natural beauty and spa supplies) as Honest.  Maybe the distinction that's been drawn between sole proprietor retail small businesses and the rarefied air of startups is not so hard and fast anymore, and maybe all it takes is an openness to possibilities to be part of the disruptive wave that's happening in technology, commerce and capitalism.  I'm wondering, anyway.

Wednesday, February 11, 2015

I don't see Greece going anywhere good...

Greece can't finance its public expenses internally on its own (at present, and given a famously corrupt system of tax collection).

But Greece isn't willing to take the actions demanded of it to enable further external lending from the eurozone.

Further lending by the eurozone, while it would improve conditions for the Greek public which is clearly hurting so badly it'll vote for anything, won't do much of anything to make Greece better able to finance itself later (through real economic growth or real reduction in corruption).

Ergo, the eurozone shouldn't lend to Greece unless Greece does take the actions required of it.

If the eurozone doesn't lend to Greece, no one else will (look demonocracy's graphic of Greek debt over the past few years for a truly sobering view).

If the Greek government has no other sources of funding, it must either default on its promises to the population, or confiscate wealth internally (and this follows logically even if somehow Greece were to continue putatively to be a member of the eurozone).

If Greece leaves the eurozone, the Greek government will be required to confiscate wealth in the form of bank capital simply to make a conversion back to the drachma possible, in addition to any confiscations required to keep their dreamy promises to their voters.

Now I understand how communist and socialist governments wind up where they do, in complete economic dead ends, even if they don't want to (and I don't think most of them do want to).

Tuesday, February 10, 2015

I got up this morning

And maybe it was because my laptop was probably destroyed when I spilled a dollop of beer on it, losing all the work I've not backed up on it in the past three years, but somehow I felt free enough to check into my blogs and add to them.  For multiple years I've been staring at them occasionally, wondering how best to deal with them -- pick up a thread? delete them? start new projects as futile as the past ones?  This morning I realized these are just places to put notes to myself, relevance not known in advance, and let the connections if any happen as they will.  Which doesn't mean the connections will happen.  Nevertheless, here I am again.

Sunday, January 27, 2013

Bendito Machine

You can watch the video here:

License to Sample, Sample as License

The style of animation references the work of Lotte Reiniger and her descendents, and going further back, Javanese shadow puppetry. This gives the animators license for a degree of "Orientalism" they might not get away with in a less clearly referential style.

The Image Barrage

There is real beauty in the video's collage of lightning fast throwaway television clips, musically syncopated and ornately choreographed. The parabolic storyline is far more primitive, or maybe I should say anachronistic, than the buildup of the images themselves, which proclaim that this way of seeing the detritus of imagery offers a line to the future.

The Cargo Cult of the Thumbnail

Why so? Because it's all been miniaturized, as in some medieval illuminated manuscript, but suitable for absorption via Iphone, to state immaterially that this is how we absorb the art of information now, it's all within the range of perception and conception now (after a couple of decades of absorbing this kind of pace via the work of makers like Martha Colburn). Why not just roll with the punches? It hurts so good.

#edcmooc

Friday, October 22, 2010

I'll be voting for Libby Schaaf

I'll be voting for Libby Schaaf for our open City Council seat in Oakland's District 4 this year.  District 4 is where I've lived since 2002, and covers a large geographical area and population, large enough that apparently we're as big just by ourselves as the city of Santa Clara.  So providing us proper representation on the Council is definitely bound to be very hard work as well as big city politics.  Jean Quan was our councilmember before this; now she's running for Mayor of Oakland, and an opportunity has opened up for the next generation of political leaders to take a place at the table. 

Out of the large group of candidates who've put themselves forward (which is in itself an honorable thing), I choose Libby because I know from having worked with her (briefly, maybe fifteen years ago, at a volunteer agency called the Marcus Foster Institute that she was managing) that she's smart and works hard, and because she offers that magical combination we Americans look for in our political leaders: she has a vision of what she thinks Oakland should be and at the same time she listens to her constituents' own visions (which sometimes contradict hers or each others) and is committed to somehow representing them as well.  Also, she knows the ins and outs of the city's political structures (which tend toward the byzantine, because of the overlay of city organizations with transit agencies, school districts, and the Port of Oakland), and has the capability of working with them in working for our district's interests.

Thursday, October 21, 2010

Confidence Game

I've been reading a few books about the credit crash recently.  I previously mentioned The Greatest Trade Ever.  Another that I finished in the last couple of weeks was Confidence Game, by Christine Richard.  I headed my Amazon review of it "A superb account of the end of the credit bubble," though of course that should have been "a credit bubble" as it's surely not the last one.  The review itself reads:

Christine Richard has managed to make a story whose end we already know, about a topic that is still arcane to most (bond insurance), a page turner as good as any suspense novel I've read lately. She combines an ability to explain the big picture and the details of the economic story with a timeless David and Goliath pitting Ackman and herself against the monstrous con that was not only MBIA, but all of the multitude interested in preserving MBIA's public image because a downgrade would be so consequential to the corruption of credit: Democratic congressmen who wanted housing for their uncreditworthy constituents, Republicans who wanted to take credit for false prosperity and keep the money coming, and especially the ratings agencies, other bond insurers, and banks. This is one of the books that should endure to tell the story of the "oughts" fifty years from now.

I sent Christine Richard a fan letter, which regrettably reuses that over-used adjective "superb" – but I did mean it:

Ms. Richard --

Your book was superb, not only a clear account of the failures and duplicities of companies most ignorant people (such as myself) thought of a "regulators" rather than financial corporations, but a lesson in how such accounting should be done, how a case should and can be made in spite of the other side's accusations, and a testament to moral courage on your and Bill Ackman's parts.

One seemingly tangential change in my own politico-economic prejudices obtains from reading your book: I'm now convinced that Obama's predecessors were guilty of an artificial economic stimulus that dwarfs those attempted in the past couple of years, and that in the future I'd prefer a straight Keynesian transfer of funds to the corruption of credit, especially if the end result in either case is to give houses to people whether they can afford them or not.

Thanks for your stellar effort!

To which she kindly responded:

Alva,
Thanks so much for writing! I'm glad you enjoyed the book.
I found your comments very insightful. Looking back it does almost seem that some universal decision was made to spread money around the economy through the "corruption of credit." Definitely a very damaging strategy!
All the best,
Christine

There's nothing better for a reader than receiving a note like that from an author one has enjoyed, is there?

Wednesday, October 20, 2010

Whole Earth Discipline

I've stopped sampling newspapers on the Kindle for the nonce – it was taking too much of my free reading time, I guess.  Instead I've been finishing some of the books I'd bought for the device, some of which, like the wonderful Richard Holmes book I mentioned in my previous post, I'd been reading from the library even before I got them electronically.  Another example of such was Stewart Brand's Whole Earth Discipline, finished a few days after the Holmes.  I've been reading Brand's books for a long time, since The Last Whole Earth Catalog in high school defined every nook and cranny of what "counterculture" could mean in Orange or Simi Valley in 1974.  I'd argue that there was always a kind of "fannish" (as in science-fiction fandom) element to his writing; certainly a sense of wonder has always been communicated, and certain of his speculations, as in The Media Lab, have been as important to my concepts of what the future might hold as a lot of science fiction.  Whole Earth Discipline continues in both the countercultural and futurist veins; most of all, it makes wonderful arguments for the virtues of being willing and able to change one's mind as one looks at the world.  Though I appreciated (and agree with) his "new-found" support for nuclear power, I found his writing on the benefits of global slums and genetic engineering more challenging and stimulating. 

Tuesday, October 19, 2010

The Age of Wonder

I made my way, always with much pleasure, through Richard Holmes' The Age of Wonder over perhaps half a year.  I checked it out at one point or another from both of my fabulous library resources (San Francisco Public and Oakland Public) and in both cases kept the book until the overdue fees started to hurt.  Finally, at something like the halfway point, I bought it for myself on the Kindle.  It's a book perfectly suited to such an occasional approach to reading because, I think, it's a large and fairly incoherent story (the rise of British and modern science in the early nineteenth century) told as a series of marvelous smaller and very coherent stories, namely, short biographies of great men.  Beginning with Joseph Banks took me right back to my first enthrallment with Patrick O'Brian's Aubrey-Maturin novels.  Banks then becomes a presiding benefactor over the whole period, and the meat of the story, for me, is in the extended biographies of William Herschel and Humphrey Davy, both of whom exemplify that intersection of artistic and scientific practice we've been discussing in incidental comments recently.  Lots of proto-science-fictional speculative thought going on in the minds of all the central figures of the period, too, from Herschel's looking for intelligences on the Moon to Humphrey Davy's final writings about consciousness in the outer planets…

Monday, October 18, 2010

The Good Man Jesus and the Scoundrel Christ

Another book read on the Kindle: Philip Pullman's The Good Man Jesus and the Scoundrel Christ, which falls like Moorcock's Behold the Man into the category of re-renderings of the Jesus story that appear from the perspective of unbelievers to be ultimately respectful, even devotional, though there's of course a difficulty for believers in seeing that to be the case.  Pullman has presented himself publicly as an atheist, but as in Dark Materials he keeps that case in the background; in both stories there is a requirement for mysterious evil persons that have something to do with institutional religions to also have powers that can't be explained, that in fact have overtones of the Satanic, and therefore to cast the worlds in which they occur as magical in ways that Pullman's real atheism wouldn't allow.  In The Good Man Jesus and the Scoundrel Christ it seems that the Devil is directly involved in the construction of the Christian narrative as we know it, from birth to resurrection through death.

The particular wit of the "Pullman version" of the Gospels is that it makes as much use as possible of the materials of the originals, but split between the stories of Jesus (which amount to the kind of nonbelievers' redaction that has a fairly long history I believe, where claims to divinity are not only discarded by rejected and the "hard sayings" to the rich and hypocritical are brought to the fore) and the back story of Christ, in such a way as to make Pullman's retelling almost credible.  As you might expect, though the character of Jesus is powerfully distilled, the character of Christ, composed shall we say of more contemporary literary glues as well as bits and pieces of the Passion narratives, held equal interest, at least in my reading.

Sunday, October 17, 2010

The Possessed

Elif Batuman's The Possessed was a very funny book, with some tinges of real seriousness.  Batuman's vignettes of eccentric academic life, especially among grad students, seemed truer to me than most popular portrayals of that world.  She captures that combination of posturing and intellectual dead seriousness that I always found intimidating at academic conferences and among graduate students in the humanities myself (as an engineering, or pseudo-engineering, grad student in Operations Research at Berkeley).  Batuman interleaves the academic story with an extended account of her stay in Uzbekistan, which I found less successful both because I didn't understand the need for the device of telling the story at such length and in three separate instalments, and also because I didn't trust that the kind of comic exaggeration of events and characters in these segments, though very much like that in the "academic parts," bore much relation to truth.  I don't know that the factualness of the events she writes about is even very important, but I couldn't get rid of the suspicion that I was reading something heavily doctored, something like journalistic stand-up comedy, in the Uzbek parts.  That said, I enjoyed the book and I think Elif Batuman has a lot of potential as a New Yorker writer in the grand manner of my favorites (among whom I count Joseph Mitchell as the absolute pinnacle of both style and content).

Saturday, October 16, 2010

The Big Short

I recently finished reading Michael Lewis's The Big Short, another of the books I've been going through having to do with the Crash of 2008.  Lewis is quick and pleasurable reading, not a detail man and not having any major ax to grind as far as I could tell (though he certainly has his prejudices, generally inclining him to the "blame greed" school of economic interpretation as far as I could tell).  The anti-social hedge fund manager Michael Burry is probably the protagonist of the book, though other "heroes" run their stories in parallel with his.  Burry, anti-social and obsessive, got his edge on the rest of the investment community by actually reading through the unreadable prospectuses, or whatever you call them, describing the detailed makeup of collateralized debt obligations and other toxic assets.  Now I believe he's buying up farm properties, according to something I saw on MSNBC a couple of weeks ago…

Wednesday, October 13, 2010

I'll be voting for Jean Quan

I'll be voting for Jean Quan for Mayor of Oakland this year, 2010.  She has represented the district I live in, District 4, in the Oakland City Council for years, much of it in leadership roles on the Council.  During the most recent period of Ron Dellums' mayoralty, which might be characterized as an absence of formal leadership, she has often served as Vice Mayor and been a crucial constructive force for moving toward a solution to the city's seemingly intractable budgetary problems. 

Jean Quan is an extremely hard worker, an attender to her constituents' retail details as well as to the city's big picture, that is to say its future and its long-term well-being.  Though a reliable liberal and Obama supporter, her approach to the affairs of the city has always been problem by problem, with full disclosure of the potential impacts of both budgetary and tax proposals on the people of the city. 

As a moderate Republican, I feel no hesitation in supporting her nonideological liberalism, which occupies an area of potential agreement and problem solution that might unite people with diverse perspectives.  And Oakland is after all one of the most liberal cities in the country; I have no desire to see someone who matches all of my own opinions elected to the city's highest office, because I don't believe such a person could get the city's varied interests to work together.

Years ago, I wrote a generic letter to Councilmember Quan, opining about this or that local issue, I don't remember exactly what, as part of some e-mail list's letter-writing campaign.  It might have had to do with our continuing need for more traffic controls on the nearby main road, but whatever it was, I do remember that Jean Quan wrote me back with a full explanation of why she wasn't able to follow "my" advice, and that she had no hesitation about explaining why her views differed from mine.  I really liked that forthrightness, and I've seen that continue throughout her term of service to the district.  I've only met her once, in passing at a Montclair Christmas shopping event, and while she seemed likeable, and not at all egotistical or sanctimonious, she wasn't what I would call charismatic.  But charismatic is not what I want in leadership of the city during this period of hardship. 

Nor do I think the kind of attempts at large-scale deal-making that Quan's main competitor, Don Perata, would probably bring to the mayoralty are the ways in which I see our problems being gradually resolved.  We've now got "ranked choice voting" in our local races, so I will put Perata down as my second choice in spite of his less preferred approach; I do think he'd do a better job than Dellums has done, at least.  But Jean Quan offers a mode of big city government that actually does give neighborhoods the power to work on their problems, and taxpayers a say in whether they'll pay more, and for what.  She is a terrific exemplar and practitioner of democratic (small d) politics.